Mittwoch, 21. Juli 2021

The economist online dating

The economist online dating


the economist online dating

The Economist is published weekly, 51 times a year, with the Christmas double issue remaining on sale for two weeks. The issue is dated Saturday and goes on sale each Friday. Intelligent Life is a bi-monthly magazine, with each issue going on sale in the month preceding the issue name. The World In is an annual publication. It is published in November and is on sale until March  · As befits a technology developed in the San Francisco Bay area, online dating first took off among gay men and blogger.com: THE DATA TEAM  · The Economist Explains; More. Newsletters; Podcasts; Video; Subscriber events; iOS app; Android app; Executive courses; Manage my account; Sign out



My Account | The Economist



Paul Oyer Paul Oyer. We asked Oyer, a professor at the Stanford Graduate School of Business and editor-in-chief of the Journal of Labor Economics, to treat us to a sampling of what he learned. He obliged with this adaptation of his chapter on statistical discrimination. Paul Oyer: As a middle-aged white male, I have it pretty easy, the economist online dating.


But I recently entered a group that, much to my surprise, made me a target of discrimination. It all started when I hit the dating scene.


The first time I posted a profile on Match. com, I was divorced in every way except the legal one. I was a Type 1 trust mebut there was absolutely no way for women poring over Match. com profiles to distinguish me from the large group of men out there who were Type 2 or Type 3.


The response to my initial profile was not overwhelming — even by middle-aged, balding economist standards. The vast majority of the emails I sent to women were ignored, the economist online dating. Several women wrote back noting that, the economist online dating, while they appreciated my honesty this, for the record, provided zero consolationthey did not date separated men because they had found that they were often not ready for a new relationship.


Now, this is certainly not the saddest story you have ever heard and, as victims of discrimination go, I realize I should not be looking for sympathy. But, as an economist, I think of this anti-separated mentality as a wonderful illustration of an important concept that has much bigger ramifications: statistical discrimination. This is the economics term for what most people would simply refer to as women acting on a stereotype based the economist online dating my separated status.


This is a much less nefarious use of the term discrimination than you are used to. It is not like Jim Crow laws or male-only clubs where the economist online dating whites or men simply do not want to associate with a group.


What makes this a classic case of statistical discrimination rather than taste-based discrimination is that women do not hold ill will towards separated men. After all, these same women will date divorced men, all of whom were separated at some point. But they discriminate against separated men because of the association between being separated and being a Type 2 or Type 3.


Racial slurs and other taste-based discrimination stem from the fact that some white people do not want to associate with black people simply because they the economist online dating black.


For example, I have a friend who returned to the dating scene a few years ahead of me after a somewhat longer hiatus. As a widower after a plus year marriage, he benefited from statistical discrimination that worked in his favor. This friend is an extremely interesting and fun person.


Nonetheless, his profile made him seem like a very, very likely Type 1. His emails to women on dating sites were generally returned, and he received many unsolicited messages because the assumptions women made about him were positive.


The statistical discrimination against my separated status led to some mild inconvenience for me and limited the pool of women I could choose from. But statistical discrimination can be much more damaging in other contexts. Example 1 : When people drive through low-income neighborhoods, the economist online dating, they often lock their car doors despite having driven long distances in other areas with the doors unlocked.


This is because they see poor people and, though they are not prejudiced against poor people per se, they associate people who are poor with those who are more likely to commit crime.


Example 2 : When hiring for a job where many of the candidates are in their 20s or 30s, firms often prefer male candidates to female candidates because women of that age are more likely to leave their jobs or take extended leaves of absence to have children. However, it is extremely frustrating for all women, especially those that have no plans to bear children, the economist online dating.


Women who do not plan to have children are pooled with women who do plan to have children and, the economist online dating, as a result, deemed less desirable by employers. Example 3 : Men are sometimes discriminated against in hiring because, as a group, they are much more likely to commit crimes than women are. Also, the economist online dating, given that young, uneducated men are much less attached to the workforce than they used to be, employers sometimes make negative assumptions about the work ethic of lower-skilled men.


Example 4 : Twenty-year-old men typically pay higher car insurance premiums than year-old women or year-old men with equivalent driving records. There are many year-old men who drive extremely cautiously, but insurance companies do not watch them driving and so, lacking information on their specific driving habits, cannot judge them by their own record.


Because, on averageyear-old men drive faster and more erratically than year-old women, these men are statistically discriminated against, even though the insurance company has no animus towards men. The highway patrol is accused of pulling over more minority drivers, and Arab airline passengers often get extra attention when going through airport security. Some of this the economist online dating is likely the result of taste-based discrimination, in that the police may be hostile to minorities and use their power to harass drivers from these groups, the economist online dating.


But there are surely many cases of police officers who are not hostile to minorities and airport security workers who are not hostile to Arabs, yet they believe with at least some empirical justification that race is positively correlated with the things they have been empowered to control. Individuals in each of these groups will be different, but the assumptions people make about each group are based on actual statistical relationships. As these examples make clear, the economist online dating discrimination is going on all around us every day and, the economist online dating, while the word discrimination conjures up images of unfairness and blameworthy behavior, a lot of statistical discrimination is tolerated.


Why does the world think it is okay for women to snub separated men while there is outrage about racial profiling at airports and on highways? Why do customers tolerate gender-based insurance rates while statistically discriminating against women in hiring is a violation of civil rights law?


There are two answers to explain this distinction, I think. But when statistical discrimination is against a group women, minorities, Arabs whose members have no control over their status, it strikes most people as unfair.


One could argue that men should qualify for sympathy on their car insurance rates since they do not choose their gender. But, either because people believe men have enough advantages in life to compensate for the car insurance expense or because men grow out of the extra insurance cost as they age, gender-based insurance pricing has generated relatively little opposition.


The second distinction between acceptable and unacceptable statistical discrimination relates to economic efficiency — that is, the degree to which statistical discrimination makes society as a whole worse off rather than only making some people worse off to the benefit of some others.


One way this could happen is if statistical discrimination leads women to underinvest in their education. Think about a firm choosing among several job candidates in their 20s, where some candidates are men and some are women. What happens if the firm chooses a man for the economist online dating job because the hiring manager thinks that the man is more likely to stay on the job for a longer time than a similar woman?


The direct effects on the parties involved just make the man who gets the job a little better off and the woman that would otherwise have gotten it a little worse off. But now think about that woman a few years earlier, when she was in college. If she understood that her career prospects would be limited because employers could make gender-based assumptions about her qualifications for a job, the economist online dating, she might work less hard or stay in school for fewer years.


That is, anticipating a lower return on her investment in college, she would reduce that investment. This decision might keep her from getting an education that would have paid off if she were able to credibly convince potential employers that she would remain active in the labor the economist online dating. The woman is hurt, but so is the economy in general; she did not make an investment that would have paid off for her and for society as a whole.


In addition to having a large effect on labor markets, statistical discrimination also has big ramifications for product markets.


There have been a number of very interesting recent studies of discrimination in product markets. One great example of this was a study done in Israel by Asaf Zussman, an economist at Hebrew University. He analyzed the discrimination of Jewish Israelis who make up a majority in the country against the Arab minority. The emails offered a price for the car that was a discount relative to the price listed in the advertisement. Zussman found substantial evidence of discrimination, as the response rate to Jewish buyer emails was much higher than the response rate to Arab buyers; an Arab buyer who offered to pay the price listed in the advertisement and a Jewish buyer who offered a 5 to 10 percent discount were equally likely to hear back from the seller.


Zussman then called each of the car sellers and administered an apparently unrelated survey that asked numerous questions about their feelings about Arabs and Arab-Jewish relations. The car sellers had no idea or, at least they were not informed that there was a connection between their car sale and the phone survey. The respondents in the survey revealed negative views of Arabs along several dimensions, with many indicating that they thought Arabs were of lower natural intelligence than Jews and should be forced to use segregated recreational facilities, the economist online dating.


All these examples, from the U. and elsewhere, are quite sobering. My own recent and short-lived experience as the economist online dating member of a group that is discriminated against has heightened my awareness of the fact that the benefits of being a middle-aged white male are widespread. Support Provided By: Learn more. Monday, the economist online dating, Jul Close Menu PBS NewsHour. The Latest. Politics Brooks and Capehart Politics Monday Supreme Court.


Arts CANVAS Poetry Now Read This. Nation Supreme Court Race Matters Essays Brief But Spectacular. World Agents for Change. Science The Leading Edge ScienceScope Basic Research Innovation and Invention.


Health Long-Term Care. Education Teachers' Lounge Student Reporting Labs. For Teachers. About Feedback Funders Support Jobs. Close Menu. Email Address Subscribe. What do you think? Leave a respectful comment. Close Comment Window. PBS NewsHour Menu Notifications Get news alerts from PBS NewsHour Turn on desktop notifications? Yes Not now. By — Paul Oyer Paul Oyer. Leave a comment. Share on Facebook Share on Twitter.


Type 3 : Devastated wrecks who are angry and bitter about their failed marriage. Additional Support Provided By:.





The Economics of Online Dating


the economist online dating

 · Yu Wang, the chief executive of Tantan, founded in and now one of China’s largest dating apps, says the country’s offline dating culture is practically blogger.comted Reading Time: 9 mins Economic and geopolitical insight guiding the world’s organisations. We work with our clients to help them navigate the increasingly complex global environment, to analyse political and economic developments, forecast economic trends, and understand country specific regulations and business practices. Enquire now  · Each week, we publish news resources designed for learners aged A range of activities help them tackle the big stories in depth and think critically in an age of fake news. If you work in a school, use them to get thoughtful discussions going in form/pastoral time. If you’re a home-educator, these can also help you embed the news into

Keine Kommentare:

Kommentar veröffentlichen

Lustige online dating geschichten

Lustige online dating geschichten Und bei diesen acht Geschichten haben wir richtig Gänsehaut bekommen. We started dating when I was lustige...